Energy Transition

This paper summarizes the spectrum of options that can be employed during the initial design and construction of pulverized coal (PC), and integrated gasification and combined cycle (IGCC) plants to reduce the capital costs and energy losses associated with retrofitting for CO2 capture at some later time in the future. It also estimates lifetime (40 year) net present value (NPV) costs of plants with differing levels of pre-investment for CO2 capture under a wide range of CO2 price scenarios. Three scenarios are evaluated—a baseline supercritical PC plant, a baseline IGCC plant and an IGCC plant with pre-investment for capture. This analysis evaluates each technology option under a range of CO2 price scenarios and determines the optimum year of retrofit, if any. The results of the analysis show that a baseline PC plant is the most economical choice under low CO2 prices, and IGCC plants are preferable at higher CO2 prices (e.g., an initial price of about $22/t CO2 starting in 2015 and growing at 2%/year). Little difference is seen in the lifetime NPV costs between the IGCC plants with and without pre-investment for CO2 capture. This paper also examines the impact of technology choice on lifetime CO2 emissions. The difference in lifetime emissions become significant only under mid-estimate CO2 price scenarios (roughly between $20 and 40/t CO2) where IGCC plants will retrofit sooner than a PC plant.

© 2007 Elsevier Ltd

Investments in three coal-fired power generation technologies are valued using the "real options" valuation methodology in an uncertain carbon dioxide (CO2) price environment. The technologies evaluated are pulverized coal (PC), integrated coal gasification combined cycle (baseline IGCC), and IGCC with pre-investments that make future retrofit for CO2 capture less expensive (pre-investment IGCC). All coal-fired power plants can be retrofitted to capture CO2 and can be considered "capture-capable", even though the cost and technical difficulty to retrofit may vary greatly. However, initial design and investment that take into consideration such future retrofit, makes the transition easier and less expensive to accomplish. Plants that have such an initial design can be considered to be "capture-ready". Pre-investment IGCC can be considered to be "capture-ready" in comparison to PC and baseline IGCC on this basis. Furthermore, baseline IGCC could be taken as "capture-ready" in comparison to PC. Cash flow models for specific cases of these three technologies were developed based on literature studies. The problem was formulated such that CO2 price is the only uncertain cash flow variable. All cases were designed to have a constant net electric output before and after CO2 retrofit. As a result, electricity price uncertainty had no differential impact on the competitive positions of the different technologies. While coal price was taken to be constant, sensitivity analysis were conducted to show the impact of varying coal prices. Investment valuation was done using the "real options" approach.
(cont.) This approach combines (i) Market Based Valuation (MBV) to valuing cash flow uncertainty, with (ii) Dynamic quantitative modeling of uncertainty, which helps model dynamic retrofit decision making. The thesis addresses three research questions: (i) What is the economic value of temporal flexibility in making the decision to retrofit CO2 capture equipment? (ii) How does the choice of valuation methodology (DCF v. MBV) impact the investment decision to become "capture-ready"? (iii) Among the coal-fired power plant technologies, which should a firm choose to invest in, given an uncertain CO2 policy? What are the economic factors that influence this choice? The answers to the research questions strongly depend on the input assumptions to the cash flow and CO2 price models, and the choice of representative cases of the technologies. For the specific cases analyzed in this thesis, it was found that investing in "capture-ready" power plants was not economically attractive.

Prediction and understanding of the regional impact of climate change in the American Midwest is of critical importance to agriculture, economy, and society. In particular, predicting the sign and magnitude of the future change in soil moisture conditions is a significant research challenge. During the summer, the input of water to the regional soil moisture (rainfall) is significantly smaller than the output from the same system (evaporation plus surface runoff). This deficit is currently supplied by drawing from the stored soil water in the saturated and unsaturated zones. Therefore, the fundamental research question raised is what will happen to the magnitude of this deficit in the coming decades? If this deficit increases significantly, e.g. due to a significant increase in evaporation, dry soil moisture conditions would develop every year at the end of the summer season. Predicting the magnitude of this deficit under climate change scenarios would require the use of models that are capable of simulating not only the right current climatology of rainfall, evaporation, and runoff, but also the right sign and magnitude of the sensitivity of these processes to climate change. Observations of the water cycle and surface energy balance from the Illinois State Water Survey and FLUXNET will be used to characterize the current climatology in Illinois and examine the sensitivity of latent heat flux to changes in available energy. Implications of the results from regional climate model simulations will be discussed in the context of global climate change and future agricultural productivity.

Wind resource in the continental and offshore United States has been reconstructed and characterized using metrics that describe, apart from abundance, its availability, persistence and intermittency. The Modern Era Retrospective-Analysis for Research and Applications (MERRA) boundary layer flux data has been used to construct wind profile at 50m, 80m, 100m and 120m turbine hub heights. The wind power density estimates at 50m are qualitatively similar to those in the US wind atlas developed by the National Renewable Energy Laboratory (NREL), but quantitatively a class less in some regions, but are within the limits of uncertainty. The wind speeds at 80m were quantitatively and qualitatively close to the NREL wind map. The possible reasons for overestimation by NREL have been discussed. For long tailed distributions like those of the wind power density, the mean is an overestimation and median is suggested for summary representation of the wind resource. The impact of raising the wind turbine hub height on metrics of abundance, persistence, variability and intermittency is analyzed. There is a general increase in availability and abundance of wind resource but the there is an increase in intermittency in terms of level crossing rate in low resource regions. The key aspect of geographical diversification of wind farms to mitigate intermittency - that the wind power generators are statistically independent - is also tested. This condition is found in low resource regions like the east and west coasts. However, in the central US region which has rich resource the condition fails as widespread coherent intermittence in wind power density is found. Thus large regions are synchronized in having wind power or lack thereof. Thus, geographical diversification in this region needs to be planned strategically. The annual distribution of hourly wind power density shows considerable variability and suggests wind floods and droughts that roughly correspond with La-Nina and El-Nino years respectively. The collective behavior of wind farms in seven Independent System Operator (ISO) areas has also been studied. The generation duration curves for each ISO show that there is no aggregated power for some fraction of the time. Aggregation of wind turbines mitigates intermittency to some extent, but each ISO has considerable fraction of time with less than 5% capacity. The hourly wind power time series show benefit of aggregation but the high and low wind events are lumped in time, thus corroborating the result that the intermittency is synchronized. The time series show that there are instances when there is no wind power in most ISOs because of large-scale high pressure systems. An analytical consideration of the collective behavior of aggregated wind turbines shows that the benefit of aggregation saturates beyond ten units. Also, the benefit of aggregation falls rapidly with temporal correlation between the generating units.

We describe several scenarios for economic development, energy use, and greenhouse gas emissions in China and India based on the MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) model, a computable general equilibrium model of the world economy. Historic indicators for economic growth, energy use, and energy intensity in China and India are discussed. In the Baseline scenario, energy use in China is projected to increase from around 60 EJ in 2005 to around 110 EJ in 2025, and energy use in India from around 20 EJ in 2005 to 40 in 2025. Alternative scenarios were developed to consider: (1) How fast might energy demand grow in China and India and how does it depend on key uncertainties? (2) Do rising prices for energy affect growth in the region? (3) Would growth in China and India have a substantial effect on world energy markets? (4) Would development of regional gas markets have substantial effects on energy use in the region and on gas markets in other regions? We also consider the implications for greenhouse gas emissions in these scenarios. Briefly, we find that with more rapid economic growth energy demand in China could reach 235 EJ and in India 95 EJ by 2025, more than twice the level in the Baseline; rising energy prices place a drag on growth of countries in the region of 0.2 to 0.6% per year; world crude oil markets could be substantially affected by demand growth in the region, with the price effect being as much as $15 per barrel in 2025; and development of regional gas markets could expand gas use in Asia while leading to higher gas prices in Europe. Greenhouse gas emissions in China and India grow from 9.3 GtCO2e in 2005 to 16.4 GtCO2e in 2025 in the Baseline scenario. Depending on the scenario, GHG emissions range from 12.5 to 36.9 GtCO2e. In the high case emissions from these two countries would be almost half of the global GHG emissions by 2025.

Climate and energy security concerns have prompted policy action in the United States and abroad to reduce petroleum use and greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions from passenger vehicles. Policy affects the decisions of firms and households, which inevitably react to changing constraints and incentives. Developing and applying models that capture the technological and behavioral richness of the policy response, and combining model insights with analysis of political feasibility, are important agendas for both research and policy. This work makes four distinct contributions to these agendas, focusing on the case of climate and energy policy for passenger vehicles in the United States.

First, this work contributes to econometric studies of the household response to gasoline prices by investigating whether or not U.S. households alter their reliance on higher fuel economy vehicles in response to gasoline price changes. Using micro-level household vehicle usage data collected during a period of gasoline price fluctuations in 2008 to 2009, the econometric analysis shows that this short-run vehicle switching response, while modest, is more pronounced for low income than high income households, and occurs on both a total distance and per trip basis.

Second, this work makes a methodological contribution that advances the state of empirical modeling of passenger vehicle transport in economy-wide macroeconomic models. The model developments include introducing an empirically-based relationship between income growth and travel demand, turnover of the vehicle stock, and cost-driven investment both in reduction of internal combustion engine (ICE) vehicle fuel consumption as well as in adoption of alternative fuel vehicles and fuels. These developments offer a parsimonious way of capturing important physical detail and allow for analysis of technology-specific policies such as a fuel economy standard (FES) and renewable fuel standard (RFS), implemented individually or in combination with an economy-wide cap-and-trade (CAT) policy. The new developments within the model structure are essential to capturing physical system constraints, interactions among policies, and unintended effects on non-covered sectors.

Third, the model was applied to identify cost-effective policy approaches in terms of both energy and climate goals. The RFS and FES policies were shown to be at least six to fourteen times as costly as a gasoline tax on a discounted basis in achieving a 20% reduction in cumulative motor gasoline use. Each of these policies was shown to have only a small effect on economy-wide carbon dioxide emissions. Combining a fuel economy standard and a renewable fuel standard produced a gasoline reduction around 20% lower than the sum of forecasted reductions under each of the policies individually. Under an economy-wide CAT policy that targets GHG emissions reduction at least cost, obtaining additional reductions in passenger vehicle gasoline use with RFS or FES policy increases the total policy cost, and does not result in 4 of 225 additional reductions in GHG emissions. The analysis shows the importance of integrated assessments of multiple policies that act on separate parts of a system to achieve a single goal, or on the same system to achieve distinct goals.

Fourth, a political analysis shows how, in the case of climate and energy policy for passenger vehicles, sharp trade-offs exist between economic efficiency and political feasibility. These tensions are shown to exist at the level of policy justification, policy type, and design choices within policies. The pervasiveness of these tensions suggests that economically-preferred policies will face the greatest barriers to implementation.

This work concludes by integrating the findings from each of the individual parts to make recommendations for policy. Recognizing the heterogeneity of household responses, the prescriptions of the economic analysis, and the tensions between these prescriptions and political considerations, policy options should be evaluated not only based on cost effectiveness, but also on their ability to serve as stepping stones toward desirable end states by providing incentives to revisit and increase policy cost effectiveness over time.

In 2003 Japan proposed a Climate Change Tax to reduce its CO2 emissions to the level required by the Kyoto Protocol. If implemented, the tax would be levied on fossil fuel use and the revenue distributed to several sectors of the economy to encourage the purchase of energy efficient equipment. Analysis using the MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) model shows that this policy is unlikely to bring Japan into compliance with its Kyoto target unless the subsidy encourages improvement in energy intensity well beyond Japan's recent historical experience. Similar demand-management programs in the U.S., where there has been extensive experience, have not been nearly as effective as they would need to be to achieve energy efficiency goals of the proposal. The Climate Change Tax proposal also calls for restricting Japan's participation in the international emission trading. We consider the economic implications of limits on emissions trading and find that they are substantial. Full utilization of international emission trading by Japan reduces the carbon price, welfare loss, and impact on its energy-intensive exports substantially. The welfare loss with full emissions trading is one-sixth that when Japan meets its target though domestic actions only, but Japan can achieve substantial savings even under cases where, for example, the full amount of the Russian allowance is not available in international markets.

© 2006 Springer Science & Business Media

In 2003 Japan proposed a Climate Change Tax to reduce its CO2 emissions to the level required by the Kyoto Protocol. If implemented, the tax would be levied on fossil fuel use and the revenue distributed to several sectors of the economy to encourage the purchase of energy efficient equipment. Analysis using the MIT Emissions Prediction and Policy Analysis (EPPA) model shows that this policy is unlikely to bring Japan into compliance with its Kyoto target unless the subsidy encourages improvement in energy intensity well beyond Japan's recent historical experience. Similar demand-management programs in the U.S., where there has been extensive experience, have not been nearly as effective as they would need to be to achieve energy efficiency goals of the proposal. The Climate Change Tax proposal also calls for restricting Japan's participation in the international emission trading. We consider the economic implications of limits on emissions trading and find that they are substantial. Full utilization of international emission trading by Japan reduces the carbon price, welfare loss, and impact on its energy-intensive exports substantially. The welfare loss with full emissions trading is one-sixth that when Japan meets its target though domestic actions only, but Japan can achieve substantial savings even under cases where, for example, the full amount of the Russian allowance is not available in international markets.

Multi-fueled electric utilities are commonly seen as offering relatively greater opportunities for reasonably priced carbon abatement through changes in the dispatch of generating units from capacity using high emission fuels, coal or oil, to capacity using lower emitting fuels, natural gas (LNG) or nuclear. This paper examines the potential for such abatement using Japanese electric utilities as an example. We show that the potential for abatement through re-dispatch is determined chiefly by the amount of unused capacity combining low emissions and low operating cost, which is typically not great. Considerably more abatement potential lies in changing planned, base load, fossil-fuel fired capacity additions to nuclear capacity. Our results are at odds with the common view that the demand for natural gas or LNG would increase, or at least not fall, as the result of a carbon constraint; and our analysis suggests that this result may not be limited to Japan.

Pages

Subscribe to Energy Transition